Do we need Shared Governance to capture Shared Value?
As corporations, industries, governments and non-profits begin to define agricultural sustainability criteria, farmers often run into an entangled accounting system. In these top-down efforts, agencies rely on USDA’s and EPA’s program and practice-driven processes. However, too often non-profits see their efforts implode when sustainability is defined, and industry reaches the same plateau as Congress – the stalemate area between discussion and decision. Some food-processors that took Porter’s “shared value” approach are making progress, but still are not integrating government, industry and non-profit efforts.
A recent AgEQA (Agricultural Environmental Quality Assurance) project in Minnesota applied a shared governance model to assist farmers to provide “reasonable assurance” that they met TMDL goals. Stakeholders aligned their conservation efforts toward a common outcome, using land-based indices as the “market signal”. The intent was for the farmers to use these ecoservice portfolios to obtain value (regulatory assurance) from the State. With this bottom-up approach, the farmer could also pursue other ecoservice values from industry, corporations, non-profits, utilities and other governmental entities. These varied assets include monetary value, market access, participatory benefits, liability reduction and resource-credits.
The relative success of the AgEQA may be seeded in the somewhat crudely worded “Carlson’s Law” that states, “due to access to cheap tools, innovation that happens from the bottom up tends to be chaotic but smart. Innovation that happens from the top down tends to be orderly but dumb.”
To capture the ecoservice values, do we need to construct a bottom-up web approach rather than rely on the top-down linear model?
Comments
Maybe another consideration
Maybe another consideration is a combination of the bottom-up and top-down approaches. That seems to be a typical recipe for shared governance. And no wonder movement is glacial: governance is messy--the disparate goals, incentives and constraints among a broad range of policy actors necessary for a workable model of shared governance predicated on shared value have to be reconciled sufficiently for benefits to outweigh costs. With that in mind, what would a practicable institutional framework look like? What sorts of incentives and assurances are needed to engage not just the providers but the other policy actors?
Sue - Yes, an integrated or
Sue - Yes, an integrated or hybrid approach would seem to be the most effective. After stumbling across the shared governance process in the AgEQA, a brief research stint revealed that the nursing-medical field and some universities have applied the model in the recent decades will limited success. It appeared that the greatest challenge in SG was including the participant that was directly correlated with the outcomes; nursing-medical was the patient, university was the student and state water quality the farmer. Interestingly, each of these models have outcomes that can be difficult to measure with traditional means; health, learning and NPS ecoservices.
A practical institutional framework to address these complex and dynamic outcomes may need to involve far more ownership/benefit of those participants that are difficult to include. The "wealth" of this institutional framework can then be determined by what resides within each of their portfolios. For example, increasing the water quality function of the natural capital of a watershed can only occur by increasing the WQ portfolio of each land manager within the watershed. The intellectual capital of a university can only be as great as that of the faculty and students.
I think the incentives need to reside and weighted at the far end of the shared governance process with assurance illustrated by imperfect indices and metrics. Those upstream up this value will begin to align themselves to receive value by assisting those at the end of the value chain. It is a complex task, but one can make a pretty good argument that the medical and conservation governance systems are not functioning - and higher education systems are experiencing some difficulties as well. The most common trait of these new governance models will emerge from the capabilities of interconnecting via social and personal networks.
Perhaps, to capture the